Зображення сторінки
PDF
ePub

rents, or the higher prices of corn which produce them, are compensated by the advantages they obtain through their vicinity to a market. In fact, the enhancement of price for the burghers or citizens is merely nominal; they obtain more, and have a readier sale, for the manufactured goods which they produce, and pay more for the corn which they consume, the one result counterbalancing the other. What matters it to the laborer, if he pays more rent for his dwelling, and a higher price for his corn and potatoes, provided that the additional wages which he receives are more than enough to meet these additional expenses? The positive gain to the community consists in the saving of transportation both ways. If the population were not concentrated, it would be necessary to transport the agricultural produce a long distance to the town where it is consumed, and to carry the manufactured goods an equal distance to the farmers who need them. Even the English economists admit, that a great saving is effected in this respect through canals, railways, and other contrivances which lessen the cost of transportation. Is it not still a greater saving to do away with the necessity of these improved means of transport, and with the cost of constructing them, by bringing the agriculturists and the manufacturers nearer to each other?

While reasoning in favor of the abolition of the corn-laws, McCulloch himself presents this point with much clearness. He argues that the repeal of these laws will not leave the English farmer destitute of protection, for he will still have an advantage over the foreign grower, consisting in the cost of importing the grain from the Baltic, the Black Sea, or America. The charges of transportation and the profits of the importer must still be added to the price of the grain at the place where it is raised, and as the risk is great in dealing in corn, this enhancement of price must be considerable. To take the nearest source of supply, for instance, he computes the cost of transporting grain from the upper provinces on the Bug to Dantzic to be from 7s. to 9s. a quarter; and thence to London, including insurance and profit, 5s. or 6s. more. If the Polish grower, therefore, receives 43s. a quarter for his wheat, "it could not, in ordinary years, be offered for sale in this country for less than from 55s. to 58s. a quarter, a price more than sufficient to insure the continued progress of British agri

culture."* If there were manufacturing cities in the southern part of Poland, the farmer there might obtain 33 per cent more for his wheat, an advantage which would more than compensate him for paying a protective duty of equal amount on manufactured goods.

It is as much for the interest, then, of the farmers of the Mississippi valley, as of the manufacturers themselves, that the American system of protection should be restored. At present, the value of the lands at the West is kept down by the distance of their produce from a market. The cost of transporting a barrel of flour from Cincinnati to New York amounts, at ordinary prices, to at least thirty per cent of its value at the former place; the cost of its further transportation to Liverpool, including insurance and other necessary expenses, raises this proportion to about forty per cent. Create a manufacturing population in Ohio like that which exists in English Lancashire, and the price of flour at Cincinnati would be made equal to its price at Liverpool. Free trade between England and Ohio, then, means simply that Ohio produce should be admitted into the English ports under what we may call a "transportation duty" of forty per cent; while, owing to the great value, in a small bulk, of the finer manufactures, English produce is to be admitted into Cincinnati at a duty of only fifteen per cent. In other words, the opponents of protection would persuade the Ohio farmer that it is better for him to buy English broadcloth at $1.70 a yard, and sell his flour at $5.00, than to buy American broadcloth of the same quality at $2.00, and sell his flour at $7.00. The depression in the value of Ohio produce, which took place between 1847 and 1852, is clearly attributable to the fact, that the crowds of laborers discharged from our unprosperous manufacturing establishments, and the 400,000 immigrants annually landed on our shores, have been driven into agriculture, and have so increased the annual product of Michigan, Iowa, and Wisconsin, as to undersell the Ohio farmer at his own door. The protection of our manufactures would enlarge the home market for him, through the very means which are now swelling the number of his competitors.

* McCulloch's Geographical Dictionary, Art. Dantzic.

CHAPTER XIV.

THE CAUSES WHICH AFFECT THE RATE OF WAGES.

THE doctrine of the English economists respecting wages may be easily inferred from their two theories, which have just been considered, respecting population and rent. Putting aside the consideration of wages reckoned in money, as these are subject to merely nominal variations, according as the value of money rises or falls, they say that wages rated in commodities, or the quantity of produce apportioned to each laborer, is determined by the ratio which the capital of the country bears to its laboring population, or to the number of those who work for hire. By capital, however, they here mean "only circulating capital, and not even the whole of that, but the part which is expended in the direct purchase of labor. To this, however, must be added all funds which, without forming a part of capital, are paid in exchange for labor, such as the wages of soldiers, domestic servants, and all other unproductive laborers."* The aggregate of capital or wealth devoted to this purpose, to the payment of productive or unproductive labor, may be termed the wages-fund of a country; and the share of it which each laborer receives will evidently be determined by its amount, compared with the whole number of persons seeking employment.

Thus explained, the doctrine is a mere truism. We obtain no insight into the causes which regulate the rate of wages, when we are merely told that this rate depends upon the whole sum annually expended for wages, divided by the whole number of persons who share this sum among them. But as it is intended to be understood, this proposition is merely a covert statement of the theory of Malthus. Assuming it to be impossible, by any measure of legislation or government policy, to increase the aggregate funds employed in hiring laborers, it is affirmed that a "diminution in the number of competitors for

* J. S. Mill's Political Economy, Vol. I. p. 401.

[ocr errors]

hire is the sole means of raising wages, and that the power and responsibility are thus placed in the hands of the laborers themselves. If they will refrain from overstocking the labor market, their condition as a class may be bettered; but " every scheme for their benefit, which does not proceed on this as its foundation, is, for all permanent purposes, a delusion." "It is impossible," continues Mr. Mill, "that population should increase at its utmost rate without lowering wages. Nor will the fall be stopped at any point short of that which, either by its physical or its moral operation, checks the increase of population."

Here is the great mistake of confounding the undue relative number of a class, with a general excess of the whole population. The former evil might be corrected by portioning out society anew, through the gradual influence of altered laws, so that the divisions or castes which are too thin in number, might be recruited from those which are in excess, and the proper balance be thus restored without the necessity of adopting any measures which would affect the bulk of the people. The latter evil, if it ever really existed, could be removed only by war, pestilence, famine, or a general adoption of the doctrine of Malthus. If it were as easy in England as it is in this country for a common laborer to become a master-mechanic, or a small tradesman, or to buy a farm; or if, as in most countries on the Continent, the bulk of the laboring community possessed either peasant properties, or a kind of prescriptive right to farm the land of another "on shares," as métayers, there would be no need of preaching abstinence from marriage to them; they would not compete with each other in the labor market, if the rate of wages were not high enough to tempt them to forsake their independent occupations. The number of persons in Great Britain who are entirely dependent on the wages of hired labor is unquestionably much too great; the proportion of this class to the whole people is probably five times as large as in any country in Continental Europe. Diminish their number, then, by all means. But how? The Malthusian economists assume that the only mode of effecting this end is to check the natural growth of the whole population, to lessen the yearly average of marriages and births. would it not be equally effectual, and more practicable, to re

cruit from them the classes which are strikingly deficient in numbers, and thus restore the proper balance of society? It is certainly an anomaly and an evil, that more than half of the people of Great Britain should be hired laborers, who have neither capital nor land; but it is equally anomalous and injurious to the welfare of the whole nation, that only about 60,000 persons should own nearly all the land,* and less than 300,000 possess four fifths of the whole property, both real and personal. If the greater part of the hired laborers in England could be converted into peasant proprietors, we should hear no

* Samuel Laing, Esq., the distinguished traveller, tells us that "the class of landed proprietors in Scotland does not, it is said, exceed five or six thousand individnals "; and in Ireland, before the recent proceedings of the Commission for the Sale of Encumbered Estates, The Times newspaper, with the best means of information, estimated the number of landholders at only eight thousand. If fourteen thousand persons own all Scotland and Ireland, it may seem extravagant to admit that there are as many as 46,000 proprietors in England and Wales. But this number includes many who own only small lots of land, sufficient for a residence and a garden; and also a few "statesmen," as they are called, in Cumberland county, who cultivate their own little farms, and are the small remains, every day diminishing in number, of the ancient "yeomanry" of England. Undoubtedly, far the greater part of the land devoted to tillage is owned by a much smaller number of persons than is here allowed. M. Léonce de Lavergne, who will not allow that property in England is so much concentrated as is commonly imagined, admits that "a certain number" of proprietors, "at most 2,000, possess among them one third of the land and total revenue; and of these 2,000, there are 50 having princely fortunes. Some of the English dukes possess entire counties, and have a revenue of millions of francs." These 2,000 families, he estimates, possess 25,000,000 acres of land, and £20,000,000 of income. The whole number of acres in the three kingdoms is 78,000,000; so that 2,000 persons own nearly one third of the land in the British Isles.

According to the census of 1851, those who returned themselves as "landed proprietors," for all Great Britain, were less than 20,000 males and 15,000 females. Of course, some were owners of land who did not return themselves in the census as such, but under the head of some occupation, as barristers, physicians, officers in the army or navy, &c. On the other hand, the rank and social importance attached to the ownership of real estate probably induced many to class themselves among the "landed proprietors," though they did not own more than a house and garden. The whole number of separate farm-holdings in Great Britain, according to the census of 1851, is 285,936. If we allow an average of six farms to an estate, which is little enough, as many noble proprietors count their tenants by fifties, we have less than 48,000 land-owners for all England and Scotland.

The estimate that less than 300,000 persons own four fifths of all the property, both real and personal, is rather vague; but as Mr. Farr, the eminent actuary, in his evidence before a committee of the House of Commons, computes from the returns under the Income Tax that there are but 236,000 persons in Great Britain who possess an income of £ 200 or upwards, the estimate probably errs only on the safe side.

« НазадПродовжити »