Зображення сторінки
PDF
ePub

did when she was a much less rich, powerful, and populous country than we now are, then indeed our condition is lamentable. The plain English of it all is that there is a great deal of nonsense and humbug in the talk about the necessity of a slow, gradual reduction of the tariff until we get down to a free trade basis (meaning a tariff for revenue only). Of course the notion is encouraged by protectionists and their organs. I am inclined to think, however, that the basis for the belief is less founded upon protectionist views than upon the innate conservatism of the American people, that, under the careful, skillful, long-continued misrepresentations of protectionists, has led them to think that downward revision of the tariff must be gradual or injury would result. In saying this, I wish it distinctly understood that I am not in favor of great and sudden reductions in our tariff duties. In deference to public opinion and the possibility of injury to vested manufacturing interests, I agree that reductions must not be great nor sudden. There is no danger they will be too great nor too sudden. The army of lobbyists in Washington, and of Congressmen with a very tender and peculiar regard for the interests of their own constituents (without which they would not be in Congress), will effectually preserve all vested rights from injury, whatever happens. But there is no lobby representing the interests of the consumers of the country, and all too

many Congressmen who want free trade in everything except in herrings. There are few who are real statesmen and can rise to the occasion and insist upon the adoption of a policy that will finally result in free trade (meaning a tariff for revenue only).

What is needed more than anything is the arousing the American people to the benefits to the whole country by the substitution of a free trade policy (meaning thereby a tariff for revenue only) in the place of the false, debasing, corrupting, enervating policy of protection that has almost succeeded in making us the economic slaves of the great trusts and other corporations. Let us put an end to the political immorality, the intellectual atrophy, and the selfish greed of protectionism.

INDEX

American colonies and protec-

tion, 100.

American people obsessed in
favor of protection, 264; need
of arousing, 287.
American Protective Tariff
League, 77.

American Revolution caused by
protective legislation, 99.
American system, the true, 3,
147; the false, 147, 151.
American Tariff Controversies
in the Nineteenth Century,
Stanwood, quoted, 10, 22, 97,
115, 127, 174, 214, 215, 216,
263, 271, 272, 285.
Annals of Congress, quoted, 36,
37.

Appleton, Nathan, on tariff dis-

asters, 143.
Asbestos, 50

Bacon, Senator, speech on the
tariff, 144; arraignment of
protectionist senators, 266.
Balance of trade theory, 27, 68,
69, 70.

Bastiat, quoted, 63-65.

Bessemer, Sir Henry, and steel

process, 251, 252.
Blaine, J. G., on the tariff of
1846, 1856, 262; on American
labor, 188.

Bounties, unconstitutional, 150.
Bowditch, J. B., and customs
receipts of 1816, 218.
Borax, results of protecting,
46, 47.

Brandeis, Lewis D., appearing
for consumers, 159.

Bright, John, on protection, 130.
Bulletin of Wool Manufactur-
ers, quoted, 229.

Business the universal, 175; de-
fined, 176.

Business interests, influence on
legislation, 110, 117.

[blocks in formation]

Carey, H. C., on protection,
139; false view of panics, 141.
Carlisle, J. G., on free trade,

9.
Carnegie, Andrew, on labor,
186.

Clay, Henry, quoted, 36; and
"the American System," 151.
Cleveland, Grover, and the Wil-
son Tariff Reform Bill, 119;
on the tariff, 182.
Cloth, deterioration of, 153, 154.
Cobb, John C., on congress as
a tariff-making body, 276.
Cobden Club, 76, 178.

Coercion, accompanying tariff
legislation, 123.

Colbert and the French mer-
chants, 61, 62; exponent of
the "mercantile theory," 68.
Commerce, chapters, 18-71; il-
lustrated, 18, 19; mercantile
theory of, 21; between men,
not nations, 21, 27; mutually
beneficial, 23, 28, 30, 53, 54;
economy of, 38, 39, 58; fet-
ters on, 39; illustration of
mutual economy, 59, 60; dim-
inished by protection, 155.
Compromise tariff of 1833, 258,
283.
Conference

Committee, arbi-

trary power of, 270, 271.
Constitution of United States
on imposts or duties, III.
Consumer, burden on through
protection, 125-127, 134-139;
yearly overcharge to, 145,
149; what he wants, 164, 165;
how he suffers, 170; foreign
consumers, 171; exploited by
mine owners, 174; annual
financial burden due to protec-
tion, 171; and woolen goods,
227, 228; heavy tax on from
protection of iron industry,
246, 250; no lobby represent-
ing, 286; despoiled by tariff
bill laws, 266; what a cent
is to, 272, 273.

Cooley, Judge, on taxes for rev-
enue, 129.

Corruption through protection,

polls, 121; of senators, 123.
Cotton, manufacturing, and
tariff of 1816, 211; growth of
industry, 212, 213, 219, 220;
beginning of spinning, 212;
meeting foreign competition,
218; weak mills apply for
protection, 219; and a low
tariff, 220; successful manu-
facturers and tariffs, 219, 221;
protection not needed by, 222-
226, 263; granted unnecessary
protection, 254; substituted
for wool, 239, 240; trans-
ferred to "Schedule C," 263.
Customs, defined, 41, 42.

Dawes Bill, 283, 284.
Democratic tariff reformers,
119, 120.
Diamonds, 51.

Dickens, Charles, on prosperity
in New England, 81.
Dingley Act, and Conference
Committee, 272.

Dolliver, Senator, appeal for
change of schedules, 266, 267.
"Dumping," the bugaboo, 65-67.

Emerson, R. W., on the basis
of political economy, 74.
England benefited by free
trade, 75; a free trade coun-
try, 75.
Excise duties, 108.

« НазадПродовжити »